From Feudalism to Capitalism: The Historical Context of Classical Political Economy
Classical political economy, wrote Karl Marx, "begins at the end of the seventeenth century with Petty and Boisguillebert."[1]
In making this statement, Marx not only identified the historical
period of the emergence of classical political economy, he also
implicitly identified the countries of its origin—England and France,
the respective homes of Petty and Boisguilbert.[2]
Classical political economy developed in England and France during the
decisive phase of the "great transformation" of Europe which ushered in
capitalist society. In one sense, classical political economy was an
intellectual product of this transformation. In another sense, as we
shall see, classical economics was also an active element in this
historic transition; it represented in part an attempt to theorize the
inner dynamics of these changes in order to shape and direct them.
Although
a certain commonality of problems associated with the transition from
feudal to capitalist society provoked the theoretical efforts of the
classical political economists, the divergent paths of English and
French development during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries
forced theorists in these two countries to conceive the problems of
economic development in markedly different ways. In England, the
emergence of agrarian capitalism during this period made analysis of
agricultural production—and especially the problem of increasing the
agricultural surplus—the central focus of British political economists.
In France, however, the rise of the absolute monarchy (and its
appropriation of a substantial share of the economic surplus) placed the
issue of the relationship between state and
― 2 ―
society
in the forefront of the concerns of French economic writers. Proposals
to reform the rural social structure were often central to their
analysis of state and society. But French agriculture failed to make the
breakthrough to self-sustaining growth experienced by England; and this
crucial fact largely accounts for the different emphases of French and
English political economists. This chapter sketches the basic patterns
of social development in England and France to illuminate the background
for the theoretical efforts of English and French political economists
in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries.
The Crisis of European Feudalism
The view that late medieval feudalism experienced a general social crisis appears to date from Marc Bloch's French Rural History,
published in 1931. Since the 1950s, economic historians have generally
identified the fourteenth century as a period of feudal crisis. Indeed,
most would accept the view of Michael Postan that western Europe
underwent an "agricultural crisis of the fourteenth and fifteenth
centuries."[3] It is further agreed that this sustained crisis was preceded by a prolonged expansion of the feudal mode of production.
The
basic historical sequence seems clear enough. After the year 800,
European feudalism underwent a slow, sometimes sporadic, but
nevertheless steady growth. In the middle of the eleventh century a
sharp and qualitatively new upswing began. Bloch quite accurately
described this period as the beginning of the "second feudal age."[4]
At the heart of this process of growth was horizontal expansion—the
reclamation of previously uncultivated land. The period from 1150 to
1240 in particular saw a major expansion of ancient villages and the
creation of new ones. Reclamation appears to have begun as a growing
population pressed against the available cultivated land. This movement
of reclamation and colonization began to exhaust itself in the middle of
the thirteenth century. Reclamation encouraged further population
growth and extended onto increasingly marginal lands. The result was a
classic case of diminishing returns: as decreasingly fertile land was
brought under cultivation, productivity and per capita yields fell.[5]
Eventually, the returns on the investment involved in reclamation could
no longer be justified. Nonetheless, population continued to rise for a
considerable period after declining productivity had put an end to
reclamation. As a result, the land-
― 3 ―
labour ratio fell as productivity slumped. The inevitable result was a crisis of subsistence.
The
fourteenth century experienced a catastrophic decline in the level of
the European population. Famines were legion throughout the century.
Moreover, an extended period of substandard diet probably increased the
susceptibility of the population to contagious disease. Certainly the
dimensions of the Black Death must have been influenced by the
deterioration of dietary standards. So disastrous was the rise in
mortality that the population of Europe appears to have been halved
between 1315 and 1380. Moreover, this was a crisis which persisted. The
evidence suggests that the European economy experienced two full
centuries of stagnation and decline. Stagnation set in during the middle
of the thirteenth century. The crisis and decline began in the first
quarter of the fourteenth century. From then on, most of Europe
experienced a downward spiral until the middle of the fifteenth century.
In other words, during the period from 1240 to 1440 European feudalism
knew little other than stagnation and decline; and for over a century
(from 1320 to 1440) it underwent a major contraction.[6]
Furthermore, so deep-rooted was this crisis of late medieval feudalism
that it carried over in much of Europe into the seventeenth century (in
some cases following a half century or so of recovery in the sixteenth
century).
The feudal mode of production contained
no self-correcting mechanisms for resolving this crisis because of the
surplus-extractive relations which characterize feudalism. Feudal lords,
as Robert Brenner has pointed out, did not have the option of
increasing their incomes through capital investments that would raise
the productivity of peasant labour and enable peasants to produce more
output during their surplus labour time. Since feudal peasants possessed
their own means of production, their economic reproduction was in a
sense independent of the surplus-extractive demands of the lords. The
production of a surplus product required extraeconomic compulsion over a
labour process which the lords did not control or direct. To invest in
improving the technical basis of this labour process would have been an
extremely risky undertaking. Furthermore, because neither lords nor
peasants depended upon access to the market for their subsistence
(although they might well enter into market transactions by choice) they
were under no direct economic pressure to produce competitively. As a
result, the drive to innovate in order to
― 4 ―
raise
productivity was absent as a general dynamic of feudal economy; the
market did not impose this necessity upon peasants or lords, and the
organization of the labour process was a disincentive to innovative
investments by the lords.[7]
The
pressure on seigneurial incomes created by crisis did not therefore
lead to investment and development. On the contrary, the efforts of
lords to raise their depressed incomes further exacerbated the crisis.
They tried to increase their incomes by squeezing the living standards
of their peasants, primarily through increased rents or labour services.
Continual pressure from the lords tended, however, to prevent the
peasants from accumulating a surplus, that is, an amount above their own
subsistence needs which would be adequate to replenish the soil and
maintain or improve its fertility. The response of lords to crisis thus
led to a decline in the productive powers of the most basic means of
production in the feudal economy—the land.
Under such circumstances the main avenue by which feudal lords could increase their incomes was distributional
struggles. Since the feudal mode of production lacked a developmental
dynamism of the sort which characterizes capitalism, lords did not
generally have the option of raising their incomes by investments
designed to increase the total social output. If a lord were to increase
his distributive share, he had to do so at the expense of his peasants
or of other lords (the latter redistribution of income requiring war).
Crisis, which heightened the downward pressure on incomes, thus tended
to unleash bitter class and intraclass struggles. As we shall see, it
was the specific, historic outcome of those struggles which shaped the
general direction of social and economic development in England and
France. In England, the ability of a section of the peasantry to improve
its situation was critical to the development of agrarian capitalism
and in the long term to self-sustaining economic growth. In France, by
contrast, the ability of the monarchy to build an absolutist state as
the last line of defence of noble power imposed a system of surplus
extraction which made sustained economic recovery virtually impossible.
England: Towards Agrarian Capitalism
Following
the decimation of the labouring population during the Black Death, the
English aristocracy launched an offensive to com-
― 5 ―
pensate
for the fall in noble incomes brought about by the reduction in their
workforce. One analyst has estimated that manorial income in the 1370s
was only 10 percent below its level of the 1340s. Since the population
had fallen by at least 30 percent, there must have been a substantial
increase in the level of exploitation of the English peasantry. This
increased exploitation stimulated widespread peasant resistance and led
ultimately to the massive peasant uprising of 1381. The rebellion of
1381 was directed against the lords' attempts to increase money rents
and to maintain village assessments for the poll tax despite the decline
in population. Although the rebellion failed to achieve its objectives,
on-going peasant resistance did win substantial economic concessions
from the lords.[8]
In these circumstances, the conditions of agricultural labourers
improved markedly. In fact, farm labourers experienced a 50 percent rise
in wages during the period 1380–1399 relative to the period 1340–1359.
Overall, there was a shift of national income away from lords and
towards peasants and labourers.[9]
Under
these conditions, the situation of the peasantry improved
substantially. Incomes rose, obligations were lightened, and a growing
amount of land was let out to peasants on a copyhold basis, which was
accepted increasingly as legal tenure under common law. As a result of
the breakup and leasing out of the big demesnes, the size of manors
contracted and on average peasant holdings grew. The fifteenth century,
therefore, has correctly been called "the golden age of the English
peasantry."[10]
At the same time that they were obtaining increased security of tenure,
English peasants were winning stable, long-term leases (often as long
as ninety-nine years) and, moreover, prices for agricultural products
were rising. Between 1500 and 1640, for example, food prices in England
rose by 600 percent. With rising prices for their marketed produce and
relatively stable money rents, many richer peasants began to accumulate a
growing surplus above their own costs of production (including
subsistence and rent). The drive to small-scale accumulation and
expansion of holdings followed logically from the ever-present threat of
contraction in bad years. Petty investment and accumulation insured
against the future; a system of simple reproduction (where the basic
drive is to maintain the peasant farm, not endlessly to expand it) does
not reproduce itself evenly over the years but, rather, through a cycle
of small-scale expansion and contraction which may always be halted
― 6 ―
by
a profound secular crisis. In the unique economic circumstances of the
fifteenth and sixteenth centuries, it was possible for petty
accumulation to become a remarkably sustained process, at least for the
better-off peasants. These peasants were able to buy up small pieces of
land and invest in livestock (the most important source of fertilizer)
and improved implements. While increased rents did take a share of the
growing output, rents generally failed to keep pace with the level of
increases in the prices of farm produce. Furthermore, the gap between
agricultural and industrial prices also moved in favour of the
agricultural producers, thus reducing their relative costs of
production.[11]
Thus, the richer peasants producing for the market were in a uniquely
favourable situation—characterized by rising prices, falling relative
costs of production, and stable or declining real rents—to use a share
of their rising income for investments that would expand their base of
production, raise the productivity of land, and increase the surplus
product in their possession. In this way, the diversion of income from
lords to peasants contributed to petty accumulation and a steady rise in
agricultural productivity.
This expansion of petty
commodity production enabled the richer peasants to emerge as
independent commodity producers, increasing the productive resources at
their disposal. Buying land from poor, indebted peasants, the top
stratum of peasant society emerged as a group of petty commodity
producers sometimes called yeomen .[12] The yeomanry has been described as "a group of ambitious, aggressive small capitalists."[13]
The term "capitalists" must be used with enormous care since, as I have
suggested, a cycle of petty accumulation could emerge within the logic
of the feudal mode of production itself and need not presuppose a new,
capitalist economic logic. Nevertheless, within an economic system
reshaped by profound crisis and a changed balance of class relations,
the yeomanry emerged as a small but dynamic rural middle stratum,
exploiting its advantage throughout the fifteenth and sixteenth
centuries to improve its social and economic position. Thus, it was
among the yeomen that enclosure first began. The early enclosure
movement involved the formation of compact fields out of fragmented
strips of land, the redivision and reallotment of land, or what Tawney
called "a spatial rearrangement of property."[14]
The bulk of enclosure by peasants was by agreement. Sometimes it also
involved a collective decision by the villagers to divide the commons;
in other cases it involved simply the exchanging or buying of land.
― 7 ―
Ironically,
it was sections of the landlord class which reaped the greatest
long-run benefits from the early enclosure movement and the rise of the
yeomanry from the ranks of the English peasantry. One effect of the
social differentiation of the peasantry was the dispossession of many
small tenants and the creation of a new class of rural poor. By the
early seventeenth century, both an indigenous gentry and an indigenous
proletariat had emerged from the newly differentiated village community.
Its traditional solidarity undermined, the village was now increasingly
divided between rich and poor. As one historian has stated, "It was the
consolidation of the yeoman oligarchies that decisively changed the
realities of village life."[15]
This transformation of the village community opened up opportunities
for those gentry and noble lords who saw a gain to be made through
enclosure on a large scale. As a result, it was these enclosing and
improving landlords who were, in the long run, to be the main
beneficiaries of those economic processes which enriched the upper
section of the peasantry and sealed the fate of the traditional peasant
village community.[16]
And it was these members of the landed class who were the main agents
in the emergence of a full-fledged system of agrarian capitalism.
From
the late sixteenth century onwards, sections of the gentry took
advantage of the weakened status of the village community to launch a
sustained offensive against the rights of the small tenants. Increasing
numbers of lords attacked peasant rights, trying to halt the decline in
their incomes as their more or less stable revenues clashed with
ever-rising prices. They attempted to break the grip of copyhold
agreements and to turn them into forms of leasehold renewable only at
the will of the lord. They drove up rents every year or every few years
("rack-renting"). They attempted to supplement income by increasing
fines and enforcing obsolete obligations. And, most important, they
undertook to enclose and reorganize lands—a path which tended to raise
the productivity of the land by 50 percent on average. Contrary to older
views which saw the eighteenth century as the great age of enclosure,
modern research suggests that by 1700 three-quarters of all enclosure
had already taken place. As a result of this multifaceted offensive,
rents doubled during the half century from 1590 to 1640.[17]
The
landlords' offensive often involved a shift to large-scale capitalist
farming in the form of pasturage as well as new crops and rotation
patterns which brought more land into productive use year in
― 8 ―
and year out.[18]
At the same time, the farm was being transformed into an economic unit
specializing in a limited number of productive activities (especially of
foodstuffs) geared to the market. More and more, the market dictated
the internal organization of the English farm: prices, profits, wages,
and rents were increasingly determined by market conditions. Having
enclosed and consolidated their estates, a growing number of landowners
rented them out to prosperous tenant farmers who hired rural labourers,
made substantial annual investments, and paid large rents. Thus emerged
the classic capitalist structure of English farming characterized by the
tripartite relationship of landlord, capitalist tenant, and wage
labourer in which the farm became a specialized productive unit geared
to the market. The landowner was now a new economic agent, one whose
wealth depended upon the surplus product of capitalist agriculture. This
transformed ruling class now sought to ensure that the property rights
and political "liberties" of landowners would be protected by (and from)
the state.
The processes described above occurred
at a time when the landed classes were growing enormously—they tripled
in size between 1536 and 1636—and in which there was a major shift of
land into the hands of the gentry. In the century after the seizure of
church lands by the Crown during the religious Reformation almost
one-quarter of the land of England was sold on the market at a cost of
six and one-half million pounds. At the same time, there appears also to
have been a flow of land from the aristocracy to the gentry between
1559 and 1602.[19]
The increasing social importance of the gentry was expressed in
political terms. During the second half of the sixteenth century, the
House of Commons grew from three hundred to five hundred members, while
the gentry's component of the House increased from 50 to 75 percent.
Following
the rise of faction and intraclass conflict that led to the virtual
breakdown of government during the middle of the fifteenth century,
Tudor governments encouraged the expansion of the power of the gentry,
in order to undermine the local power of large nobles. A stable and—at
least initially—self-sufficient monarchy was constructed by the early
Tudors, who used increased parliamentary representation and low levels
of taxation to win the gentry's support as an important counterbalance
to the traditional power of the upper nobility. The Tudor monarchy,
therefore, relied increasingly on new
― 9 ―
sources
of landed wealth and political power in exchange for concessions to the
gentry, such as low taxation and increased powers at the local level,
particularly in the administration of justice. The result was a
significant weakening of the independent powers of the Crown, a
strengthening of the political power of the landed proprietors, and a
departure from the absolutist path.[20]
By the beginning of the seventeenth century, then, England was
undergoing the transition to agrarian capitalism in the context of a
nonabsolutist state which relied upon the participation of broad
sections of the landed classes in the affairs of state. Participation of
landed gentlemen in the exercise of political power was increasingly
seen as a right which flowed directly from ownership of property. Such
"liberties" were considered inherent rights of property. Thus, any
attack on the participation of landed gentlemen in affairs of state was
seen as an attack on property itself.
The Stuart
reaction of 1603–1640 was a response to the dispersion of political
power in England and an attempt to reconstruct centralized monarchical
power. In part, the English Revolution can be seen as a rebellion by
landed gentlemen against this tendency towards absolutism and in defence
of rights that had been won during the previous one hundred fifty
years. To be sure, significant sections of the landed class perceived
rebellion against the Crown to be a greater danger than absolutism,
since it might ignite a rebellion of the lower orders against authority
and property. But it seems fair to say that, although many opposed the
road of revolution, the majority of landed gentlemen were markedly
hostile to absolutism. Thus this "bourgeois revolution" was a revolution
against centralized state power. This characteristic of the English
Revolution is perfectly explicable if we see it as an attempt by
agrarian capitalist landowners to preserve and protect their property
rights, their newfound forms of surplus extraction (and these very
surpluses themselves), and their right to participate in the "committee
of landlords" ruling England at the local level and increasingly shaping
events at the national level (and which they perceived as vital to
protect their property and their rents).[21]
The
"revolution from below" unleashed by the English Civil War did indeed
pose a threat to the traditional privileges of men of property. The
popular mobilizations in London and other cities, the formation of
Parliament's New Model Army, the abolition of monarchy and the House of
Lords, and the execution of the king all contrib-
― 10 ―
uted
to an often-millenarian sense that the old order was finished and that
it would be replaced by a democratic and highly egalitarian form of
society.[22]
Faced with such an upsurge of popular radicalism and an army drawn from
the lower orders which opposed a return of the traditional social
order, the bulk of the propertied class chose to support a restoration
of monarchy and the House of Lords. Even then, however, when Charles II,
who took the throne in 1660, attempted to pursue an absolutist policy,
he incited the great wave of Whig agitation of 1679–1681 against the
court, which culminated in 1688 in the overthrow of his successor, James
II.[23]
The
drive against the independent powers of the monarchy became even more
powerful following the Glorious Revolution of 1688. Despite the fact
that 1688 was an event carefully orchestrated to avoid renewed rebellion
from below, and despite the fact that the Bill of Rights of 1689 did
not go nearly as far as the Whig radicals desired, the bill reinforced
the trends towards limiting the powers of the Crown by making
extraparliamentary taxation illegal; by ensuring that there should be no
standing army without parliamentary approval; and by abolishing the
Crown's suspending and dispensing powers.[24]
The Triennial Act of 1694 guaranteed regular parliaments and abolished
the royal prerogative of summoning and dissolving Parliament. Finally,
the Act of Settlement of 1701, subtitled "an act for the further
limitation of the Crown and the better preserving the liberties of the
subjects," provided that the tenure of judges would be permanent,
subject only to good behaviour, and not dependent upon the Crown.
Having
achieved a state responsive to their interests, after 1688 the large
landowners moved with a passion to enclose and concentrate holdings.
Between 1690 and 1750 there was a major shift of property away from the
peasantry and lesser gentry and towards the large landowners. The
century after 1690 experienced a dramatic decline in the percentage of
land held in farms of less than one hundred acres and a sharp rise in
the share held by farms of one hundred acres or more. This shift in land
ownership involved a doubling of rents, in part a result of the
increased productivity of the land brought about by enclosure and
improvement.[25]
For financial considerations such as these, landlords turned to
enclosure on a vast scale. Having taken the reins of government into
their hands, they used acts of Parliament to legalize expropriation that
has been accurately described as a
― 11 ―
"massive violence exercised by the upper classes against the lower."[26]
In 1710 the first private enclosure act was presented to Parliament.
Between 1720 and 1750, 100 such acts were passed. Some 139 acts followed
in the subsequent decade. Another 900 acts were passed between 1760 and
1779. The movement reached its peak between 1793 and 1815, when 2,000
acts of enclosure were approved by Parliament. As a result, over the
eighteenth and nineteenth centuries more than 6.5 million acres of
common fields and commons were enclosed by acts of Parliament—an area
equal to nearly 20 percent of the total land of England. In some areas,
the amount of land enclosed went as high as 50 percent of the total. The
change was thus massive—and, for the small tenant, catastrophic.[27]
Modern
historical research has demonstrated the shortcomings of the view that
enclosure directly provided the labour force for urban
industrialization. In reality, the majority of those who suffered at the
hands of enclosure appear to have stayed on the land. This fact has led
some writers to claim that the dislocation caused by enclosure has been
exaggerated; they have asserted that enclosure and innovation provided
work for those members of rural society who no longer held sufficient
land or access to land (for example, commons) to support themselves. In
this interpretation, enclosure was a largely technical process which
benefited most members of the village community through higher levels of
output and new prospects for employment.[28]
Such an approach so minimizes the social consequences of enclosure as
to distort the whole process. Whatever the shortcomings of some Marxist
interpretations of the relationship between enclosure and
industrialization, the great strength of the Marxist approach has been
to see in enclosure a crucial element in a process of social
transformation in which the fabric of traditional rural society was rent
asunder and a new social structure, based on a propertyless
proletariat, created. Enclosure was, after all, as W. G. Hoskins
described its effects on the Leicestershire village of Wigston, "the
destruction of an entire society with its own economy and traditions,
its own way of living and its own culture."[29]
What
took place in England during the sixteenth, seventeenth, and eighteenth
centuries is what Marx described as the "primitive accumulation of
capital." In a nutshell, primitive accumulation refers to those
historical processes by which direct producers were separated from the
land and transformed into "free" wage labourers.
― 12 ―
The
freedom of wage labour was for Marx a two-sided phenomenon: on the one
hand these workers were "freed" from the land—they neither owned nor
controlled means of production adequate to their own subsistence; on the
other hand, they were juridically "free" individuals able to enter
voluntarily into an agreement to work for an employer. At the heart of
primitive accumulation, therefore, is "the historical process of
divorcing the producers from the means of production." The separation of
labourers from means of production is the crucial historical process
which makes capitalist accumulation and production possible. Primitive
accumulation creates the unique commodity, labour power that is bought
and sold on the market, which distinguishes capitalism from all other
modes of production. The creation of a propertyless class of wage
labourers establishes the social relationship within which capitalist
exploitation and accumulation can develop. The great strength of Marx's
analysis was to recognize the critical importance of this social
relationship and to grasp the historical fact that "the expropriation of
the agricultural producer, of the peasant, from the soil is the basis
of the whole process."[30]
However,
those most directly affected by enclosure did not, as many early
Marxists believed, move in large numbers to urban centers to labour in
the workshops of the industrial revolution. Their rural existence was
nonetheless radically altered; they became the rural proletariat of the farms and village industries. What many Marxists have failed fully to appreciate is that agrarian capitalism
formed the connecting link between primitive accumulation and
industrial capitalism. By agrarian capitalism we refer to that situation
in which large farms (usually of two hundred acres or more) were leased
out to prosperous tenant farmers who hired wage labourers; and produced
an agricultural product for sale on a market. The surplus above costs
of production (including wages) was then divided between the farmer and
the landowner in the forms of profit and capitalist ground rent (as Marx
called it). Primitive accumulation thus contributed directly to the
creation of a rural proletariat and a system of agrarian capitalism.
Having
said this, we must emphasize that the development of agrarian
capitalism was neither as direct or unambiguous a process as the
economic data alone might suggest. The emergence of agrarian capitalism
was constrained by the traditional force of customary rights, to which
the small tenant and labourer clung tenaciously. In a
― 13 ―
very
real sense, the full flowering of agrarian capitalism in the eighteenth
century represents the victory of property rights over customary
rights; but the complete victory of property over custom took place only
over centuries in the course of often bitter social conflicts. Agrarian
capitalism was anything but a pure social species which leaped fully
formed onto the stage of history. On the contrary, it emerged in a
hesitant—but nonetheless forcible and sometimes violent—step-by-step
process in which it was invariably coloured by the traditional society
it was leaving behind.[31]
Proletarianization
occurred in a context in which customary rights continued to play an
important part in the lives of the direct producers. In the sixteenth
and seventeenth centuries in particular, perquisites and customary
rights on common lands constituted a significant supplement to the wage.
Such rights and perquisites to some extent kept the village labourer
from complete subjection to the vagaries of the labour market. For this
reason, village labourers objected not so much to their status as wage
labourers but rather to those measures which threatened to eliminate
such customary rights. This objection is only natural, given that the
disappearance of such rights represented their complete
proletarianization, the restriction of their sources of livelihood to
the price which they could command for their ability to work. It
represented, in other words, their total subordination to the rhythms of
the capitalist labour market. The parliamentary enclosure in the
eighteenth century, therefore, centred as it was on common lands, truly
completed the process of proletarianization. For this reason we can echo
E. P. Thompson's statement that in the eighteenth century "agrarian
capitalism came fully into its inheritance." For it was then that the
conflict between property rights and customary rights was resolved
decisively in favour of the former.[32]
The
growth of large farms and the displacement of small tenants also
expanded the home market. The decline of self-sufficient family farming
and the growth of specialization forced capitalist farmers, labourers,
and landowners to turn to the market to meet their needs for producer
and consumer goods. In large measure, the rural proletariat (including
semiproletarianized cottagers and the like) provided the labour force
for those industries which grew up in response to the demands of
England's growing domestic market. In active farming areas, local
industries grew up which were devoted pri-
― 14 ―
marily
to the production of farm and domestic products. Lace-making,
straw-plaiting, nailing, needle-production, paper-making, and
framework-knitting were the most common industries in such areas. The
most significant economic growth took place in less arable areas, such
as the Midlands. Here tanners, leatherworkers, fullers, weavers,
shearers, clothworkers, and ironmongers dominated the industrial scene.[33]
During the sixteenth century, increasing numbers of yeomen and small
farmers were drawn into industries such as these. And in the seventeenth
and eighteenth centuries, displaced peasants often found employment in
these trades as agricultural specialization increased demand for these
industrial products. The decline of rural self-sufficiency thus
increased the industrial market. In this way, the growth of agrarian
capitalism accelerated the growth of an industrial market.
The
growth of agricultural productivity, especially during the eighteenth
century, played a decisive role in expanding the home market and more
than doubling corn exports in the first sixty years of the century.
Unprocessed agricultural products as a share of English manufactured
exports rose from 4.6 percent in 1700 to 11. 8 percent in 1725 and to
22.2 percent by 1750. During this same period, there was no significant
increase in industrial exports. As output grew, corn prices fell. In
fact, by the 1730s and 1740s, prices were 25 to 33 percent lower than
the average for the 1660s. Lower prices for corn contributed to a rise
in the real wage and thus brought about an increase in the demand by
labourers for domestic manufactures. The terms of trade also moved in
favour of manufacturers and gave a boost to the industrial sector, in
relatively lower costs of production. By the 1750s, there was a
permanent flow of population from the countryside to urban centres like
London, Birmingham, Sheffield, and Manchester. Agricultural improvement
was thus contributing to the growth of an urban proletariat.[34]
At
a certain point—recent research has suggested the 1760s—the expansion
of markets and high labour costs induced manufacturers to introduce
labour-saving machinery of production .[35]
And, once introduced, machinery became central to the process of
accumulation. Technological innovation designed to reduce costs became
an integral part of capitalist competition. Industrial capitalism—what
Marx called "the specifically capitalist mode of production," in which
the machinery of production is continually revolutionized in an effort
to
― 15 ―
raise productivity[36]
—thus became the order of the day. England had crossed the frontier
into the age of modern capitalism. Agrarian capitalism had, however,
been the vessel of its crossing.
France: The Rise of Absolutism
The
French nobility was confronted with the problem of declining rents from
the middle of the thirteenth century onwards. Peasants enjoyed
significant success in struggles over the distribution of output and
over access to common woods, pastures, and fisheries; the result was
shrinking seigneurial incomes. During the fourteenth and fifteenth
centuries, village communities won a corporative status that enabled
them to defend their rights. Under conditions of expanding agricultural
markets, improved prices for farm products, and a relaxation in the
burden of the taille, a stratum of middling peasants emerged who reaped the benefits of prosperity.[37]
In
order to counteract these trends, during the second half of the
fifteenth century the French nobility launched a localized offensive
which picked up steam throughout the sixteenth century. In many parts of
France, customary grazing rights came under attack. In response to this
offensive and to the growth of rural poverty, peasants erupted
episodically during the 1540s into resistance they directed especially
against various forms of royal taxation. The drift towards anarchy
throughout the course of the religious wars was punctuated by major
peasant risings between 1578 and 1580. In the midst of widespread famine
and economic crisis during the 1590s, massive peasant rebellions shook
the social structure of sixteenth-century France. The scale of these
uprisings forced the landed ruling class to put its internal differences
behind it and to unite against the threat from below. The result was a
decisive shift in the direction of monarchical absolutism.[38]
Absolutism thus represented, as Perry Anderson has written, "a
redeployed and recharged apparatus of feudal domination, designed to
clamp the peasant masses back into their traditional social position."[39]
Unable to break peasant resistance and to raise levies at the local
level, the lords turned to the concentrated power of the centralized
state.
Once the absolutist state was set on a
secure footing following the civil wars and peasant revolts of the
sixteenth century, the political and military weight of a centralized
administrative machine was capable of ensuring a substantially increased
level of peasant exploita-
― 16 ―
tion. Between 1610 and 1644, for example, state exactions from the taille
rose from 17 million to 44 million livres. Total taxation quadrupled in
the decade after 1630. These increases represented a rise in the real
level of exactions as grain prices stagnated during this period. By
1628, in fact, Normandy alone was providing Louis XIII with revenues
equal to all those raised by Charles I in England. By the time of Louis
XIV's first war (1667–1668), the French Crown was raising 60 million
livres in revenue; no other European power, except Holland, could count
on an income a quarter of that amount.[40]
However, though absolutism preserved the social relations of feudal
exploitation, it did so in a fashion which created new social conflicts
and constructed major obstacles to economic development.
The
most obvious conflict engendered by absolutism was that between the
surplus-extractive demands of the local lords and those of the state.
Inherent in the distribution of the surplus product was a conflict
between rent and taxes, the latter a "centralized feudal rent" drawn
from the seigneurie of the whole realm. Especially in bad years, state
exactions could entirely eliminate seigneurial rents. As a result, lords
often encouraged peasant resistance directed against tax collectors or
their agents.[41]
In
order to avoid a full-scale confrontation between the aristocracy and
the absolutist state, the Crown strove to integrate sections of the
ruling class into the machinery of taxation. The most effective means of
doing so was through the sale of offices, which would give their owners
a share of the centralized feudal rent exacted by the state. These officiers
of the state would thus come to identify with the tax system as an
important source of their personal wealth. Through the sale of offices
the absolutist state provided itself with a measure of stability, since
"it could absorb into state office many of those very same lords who
were the casualties of the erosion of the seigneurial system."[42]
The sale of offices also had another significant effect for the Crown:
it provided the state with a source of wealth separate from the surplus
product of the peasantry and thus—at least in principle—lessened the
direct conflict between rent collection and taxation. Moreover, to the
extent to which bourgeois wealth was drawn into the purchase of offices,
the Crown was able to tap a financial source largely independent of
feudal exploitation.
The sale of offices served as a
short-term solution to the basic structural problem of French
absolutism. The absolutist state was
― 17 ―
plagued
throughout its history by a chronic inability to raise revenues
sufficient to pay its basic costs—especially the costs of war. War
forced the state to resort to even more extraordinary measures in an
effort to meet its expenses; it relied increasingly on loans. In
receiving loans from financiers and wealthy nobles, the Crown agreed in
turn to alienate specific revenues from the tax system. While the system
of loans enabled the monarchy to meet pressing expenses, its longer
term effect undermined the financial strength of the state. The result
was that absolutism experienced a sharp conflict between the Crown and
those officeholders who claimed a share of royal revenues. So desperate
became the situation of the Crown that it often sold fraudulent rights
or imaginary supplements to the salaries of officiers . And so intense did the conflict between officiers and the Crown become that it at times erupted into open insurrection.[43]
A basic contradiction thus ran through the structure of French absolutism: the conflict between Crown and officiers
. It was a conflict which could not be resolved. On the one hand, the
monarchy needed a stratum of nobles and bourgeois whose private wealth
it could tap. On the other hand, however serious their grievances, the officiers
could not fundamentally challenge the absolutist régime; to do so would
have deprived them of access to the potential fortunes to be made
through participation in the fiscal apparatus of the state. On its own,
perhaps, this basic contradiction could have been tolerated. In the long
run, however, the extraordinary financial machine of French absolutism
siphoned enormous amounts of wealth out of productive activity and into
the purely speculative area of state investments. In so doing, the
fiscal machine erected an insurmountable obstacle to revitalization of
the French economy.
The main focus of bourgeois
investment in the eighteenth century was what George Taylor has called
"court capitalism," which term refers to "the exploitation by
individuals and syndicates of government farms, state loans, and
joint-stock flotations and speculations."[44]
"Court capitalism" revolved around the speculative activities of
financiers, those who were private agents in the collection of state
revenues as farmers general, treasurers, and receivers general of
finance in the provinces and those who advanced loans to the Crown in
exchange for office and rentes . In reality, the term is a
misnomer. Porshnev's notion of a "feudalization" of the French
bourgeoisie is more accurate. In one form or another, through loans
either to nobles
― 18 ―
or
to the state, enormous amounts of bourgeois wealth were advanced to the
traditional ruling class in exchange for a share of feudal dues from
either the local or central level. These feudal dues became a form of
interest payment on capital advanced as credit. In this way, bourgeois
incomes became dependent upon the system of feudal surplus extraction.
Without doubt, the greatest fortunes were to be made through investments
in the fiscal machine. In addition, the purchase of venal office could
provide noble status while further investments could acquire fiscal
exemption and seigneurial rights. The speculative fortunes to be made
from lending to the Crown or participating in joint-stock enterprises
were immense and stimulated an intricate network of intrigue and
influence peddling; state-related investments thus dominated bourgeois
pursuit of wealth and status. Consequently, commercial wealth did not
flow into productive investments in agriculture and industry, since "the
most spectacular operations of old regime capitalism were made possible
by royal finance and political manipulation rather than industrial or
maritime enterprise."[45]
But
perhaps the major obstacle to economic development posed by absolutism
had to do with its effects upon the peasantry and the system of
agriculture. As in England, significant social differentiation did occur
in the ranks of the peasantry during the fifteenth and sixteenth
centuries. Unlike England, however, this differentiation did not in
France proceed to the point at which a yeoman stratum emerged from the
ranks of the peasantry and undertook a form of petty commodity
production. The reason for this seems clear: the consolidation of
absolutism enabled the state to significantly increase the level of
exploitation of the peasants. By raising the level of exploitation, the
royal power prevented peasants with larger holdings from amassing
surpluses sufficient to improve the productivity of the land, to expand
their holdings, and to set in motion the bare beginnings of a genuine
agricultural revolution.
Just as absolutism tended
to block the emergence of a commodity-producing stratum of rich
peasants, so it tended to close off the possibility of lords enclosing
land and moving in the direction of agrarian capitalism. Absolutism
heightened peasant exploitation; at the same time it also buttressed
peasants' rights to property and defended the peasantry against
excessive exaction by local lords. The Crown saw clearly that marked
rises in rents would prevent full pay-
― 19 ―
ment
of taxes. Furthermore, since the nobility was exempt from taxation, the
Crown had a direct interest in the preservation of the peasantry—its
primary tax base. As a result, peasants generally received support from
the monarchy and especially from its local representatives, the
intendants, in their campaigns against enclosures by landlords. For this
reason, according to Bloch, "the victory of the absolute monarchy kept
the 'feudal reaction' within bounds."[46]
Absolutism thus defended the property rights of the peasantry while it
heightened exploitation of peasants; and while it blocked the emergence
of a prosperous stratum from the ranks of the peasantry, it put major
obstacles in the way of agricultural improvement and enclosures by
landlords.
Nobles did attempt to enclose,
consolidate, and undermine the traditional rights of the peasantry. And
in some cases they did demonstrate an orientation to commercial farming.[47]
But none of these movements succeeded in transforming France's rural
social structure—nor could they have, given the nature of feudal
absolutism. Unable to change the social relations of agricultural
production, through primitive accumulation, and thereby to boost surplus
product with innovations designed to maximize output, the French
nobility were left with no real option but to squeeze a greater surplus
from essentially unchanged levels of peasant output.
Thus,
while absolutism preserved the power of the nobility—in a dramatically
altered form—it also undermined the long-term strength of the economy
upon which that power rested. The result was that peasants failed to
meet the requirements of simple reproduction, to replace the seed,
tools, livestock, and labour necessary to sustain a standard level of
productivity; and the vitality of the economy was sapped. Consequently,
the productivity of the land declined. At the same time, rural poverty
blocked the development of a growing home market for domestic
manufactures. The maintenance of a mass of small peasant holdings thus
guaranteed that absolutist France would not make a breakthrough to
self-sustaining economic growth. The sapping of economic vitality also
undermined the power of the absolutist state. An impoverished peasantry
could not endlessly provide the revenues necessary for a massive,
centralized state. Periodic crises, which became endemic by the 1690s,
forced the monarchy to tax noble wealth. Yet in so doing the Crown
threatened its own often tenuous base of support in the ruling class.
The eco-
― 20 ―
nomic
and fiscal structure of absolutism thus generated a series of economic
and political contradictions, all of which conspired to prevent a
capitalist transformation of the agrarian sector and thereby to block a
breakthrough to self-sustaining economic growth. In this way, economic
crisis sowed the seeds of political crisis.
In
1758—when the physiocratic school first rose to prominence—France was
facing a threefold crisis. Her armies were reeling under a series of
defeats that were to result in the loss of the Seven Years' War. Foreign
trade was ruined and the financial crisis reached alarming heights.
Payment of inscriptions was suspended, salaries were stopped,
and people were urged to bring in their gold and silver ornaments for
minting. By this point, absolutism had run its course. The economy was
impoverished, the state effectively bankrupt. Theorists like the
Physiocrats saw one way and one way alone out of the crisis: an
English-style capitalist transformation of the agricultural sector. The
physiocratic revolution was not to be, however. The result was that the
monarchy stumbled from one crisis to another. By 1789, the annual
deficit equaled one-fifth of the state budget while interest payments on
the national debt rose to more than half of annual government
expenditures.[48]
Inability to solve these economic dilemmas of absolutism sealed the
fate of the régime, contributing powerfully to the revolutionary crisis
of 1789. However, the failure of agrarian revolution continued to haunt
the French economy long after absolutism had been laid to rest.
Conclusion
Classical
political economy, as we noted at the outset of this chapter,
originated in England and France in the second half of the seventeenth
century. It was during this period that the course of social and
economic development for the subsequent century was largely determined.
And it was the prospects and problems posed by these patterns of
development that occupied the attention of the classical political
economists.
In the case of England, the seventeenth
century was the century of revolution and of the rise of agrarian
capitalism. Transformation of the agrarian social structure was a
central feature of this period; the Revolution served ultimately to
accelerate this process by fashioning a state which increasingly served
the interests of capitalist landowners. Within the structure of agrarian
capitalism, rent was the
― 21 ―
dominant
economic surplus and its utilization the key to economic development.
It should come as no surprise (to anticipate the next chapter) that the
central concern of British political economists of the seventeenth
century was understanding those processes which created and increased
the rents accruing to the owners of the land.
In
France, as we have indicated, consolidation of monarchical absolutism,
while preserving noble power, erected major obstacles to economic
development. By raising peasant exploitation, absolutism impoverished
the rural economy. By defending the rights of peasant ownership, it
blocked seigneurial attempts to enclose and consolidate farms and to
organize agricultural production on a new basis. Finally, in
"feudalizing" the bourgeoisie by integrating it into the apparatus of
state credit and finance, it directed non-noble wealth into unproductive
channels. The overall result was that a sustained recovery was not
triggered and that, every time the lords or the state increased
exactions, economic catastrophe loomed.
These
economic contradictions of absolutism fundamentally destabilized the
monarchy. The financial well-being of the state depended ultimately on
the health of the economy. As absolutism undermined the latter, it
signed its own death warrant. The most dramatic feature of the crisis of
absolutism was its fiscal aspect—the crisis of state revenues. For this
reason, the problem of taxation was the central concern of French
political economists during this period. The more perceptive theorists
recognized, however, that the system of taxation could be reformed in
any lasting way only if the economic system—and its agrarian sector, in
particular—were radically transformed. The problems of taxation and
economic development were intimately connected.
Rent
and taxes were thus the major economic categories which dominated the
writings of the pioneers of classical political economy. How these
categories were constructed, and their place in a general model of
economic relations, is the topic of the next chapter.
― 22 ―
Chapter One From Feudalism to Capitalism: The Historical Context of Classical Political Economy | ||||||||